Ficool

ECONOMIA

Daoistw2m8DC
7
chs / week
The average realized release rate over the past 30 days is 7 chs / week.
--
NOT RATINGS
156
Views
Table of contents
VIEW MORE

Chapter 1 - Cap1-3

Schumpeter was a man of many interests as well as talents. Beyond that he had,

certainly as a young man, monumental ambitions. It is not appropriate in this essay to

devote much space to the journey of his life; fortunately there are now available not only

the 1950 insightful memorials by his colleagues, particularly the one by Gottfried

Haberler,1

a massive as well as a magnificent piece of bibliographical scholarship on

what he wrote, who wrote about him, and with whom was he most frequently compared

by Massimo M.Augello (1990),2

but also three recent (1991) and assuredly major

biographies of the man. Schumpeter, A Biography by Richard Swedberg contains a

particularly carefully balanced, scholarly assessment of

*

Thanks are owed to several friends who have read and corrected the manuscript: Professors

A.W.Coats, Warren Samuels, Yuichi Shionoya, Richard Swedberg and Shigeto Tsuro, and Dr

Charles McCann.

1

This essay appeared originally in the Quarterly Journal of Economics. It was reprinted in

Seymour Harris's edited volume, Schumpeter, Social Scientist (Harris, 1951) and again in Haberler

(1993). The 1951 volume also contained essays by 16 leading economists, including inter alia

Ragnar Frisch, Arthur Smithies, Paul A.Samuelson, Jan Tinbergen, and Fritz Machlup. 2

Augello cites 260 works (including articles and books translated into languages other than the

original) by Schumpeter and 1916 works on Schumpeter. Augello's own generalizations or findings

are in a comprehensive 93-page essay, replete with valuational (that is, Augello's straightforward

evaluations) notes. I am not aware of a comparable task done recently by any economist on an

economist.

Schumpeter's four or five major efforts as well as an intriguing general account of the

times and environments in which he lived. Swedberg discusses ad seriatim the various

decades of Schumpeter's life and work, and if he attempts to explain the man, he does so

only by inference.

The second biography is different. Opening Doors: The Life and Work of Joseph

Schumpeter by Robert Loring Allen has more of the characteristics of James Boswell's

The Life of Samuel Johnson, LL.D. or Samuel Pepys' Diary (1815). Benefitting greatly

from the massive, scholarly, even daunting3

task of deciphering Schumpeter's personal

diaries undertaken by Mrs Erica Mattschnigg Gershenkron,4

Allen interpreted the often

elliptical, if not actually obscure, materials. Unlike Swedberg (a sociologist), Allen (an

economist) was a much-impressed, even overwhelmed, Schumpeter student. Allen

documents much of what Swedberg could do no more than infer.

The third biography, Joseph Schumpeter: Scholar, Teacher, and Politician by Edward

März, a Viennese Marxian historian, eschews not only discussion of Schumpeter, the

idiosyncratic individual, but virtually all mention of Schumpeter's historico-culturalepistemological interests. März's effort is to fit Schumpeter into the ranks of latter-day

Marxians, an interesting effort but one hardly germane to what we are interested in. For

that reason, what follows is based in large measure on the memorials and the other two

studies.

1.2 I believe that Schumpeter's intellectual efforts centered on five (possibly four and

a half) major projects. I would classify the first burst of effort (including three books) as

at least two major projects, one involving the nature of economic theory and economic

science and the other concentrating on the nature and sources of economic development.

The first surfaced in the 1908 Das Wesen und der Hauptinhalt der theoretischen

Nationalökonomie (The Nature and Essence of Theoretical Economics) and to a lesser

degree in the 1914 Der Dogmen- und Methodengeschichte (Economic Method and

Doctrine: An Historical Sketch)5

; the second in the 1911 Theorie der wirtschaftlichen

Entwicklung (The Theory of Economic Development).

His next (I would term it the third) major effort involved a book on money (partly

written but never published by him although it did appear in 1970 as Das Wesen des

Geldes6

) and his 1939 two-volume Business Cycles. This generally unsuccessful effort

paralleled Maynard Keynes's 1930 abortive Treatise on Money and his thoroughly

successful 1936 General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money.

Schumpeter did not think that his Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy was a major

effort; indeed he 'often called it a "pot-boiler"' (Allen, 1992, II, p. 133). Others have not

shared that assessment, and it may well be termed Effort 'Three and a Half' or even Four.

3

The task was daunting because much was written, even scribbled, in an archaic German

shorthand.

4

I am indebted to Professor Yuichi Shionoya for this information and other points, too. 5

This book was essentially the basis for the last effort. However, as Schumpeter thought all study

of economic theory involves knowledge of its origins, at the time (pre-World War I) he linked the

two.

6

Edited and introduced by F.K.Mann. Göttingen: Vandenhöck & Ruprecht, 1970, pp. xxvii, 341.

His fifth effort involved his interpretation of the filiation of ideas in the development

of economic theory. This effort surfaced initially with his 1914 Epochen der Dogmen—

und Methodengeschichte (translated later as Economic Doctrine and Method: An

Historical Sketch) and was unfinished when he died, but the outline of the corpus

appeared as History of Economic Analysis (1954). I would also include in this fifth effort

another posthumous collection, Ten Great Economists (1954), which contains polished

essays.

1.3 The unfinished History of Economic Analysis (HEA) is the most significant part of

the fifth and last of Schumpeter's great projects. To some, its development represents the

somber reflections of an older scholar, one embittered by personal, career, and character

tragedies. To others, it is the quintessential, if uncompleted, final great professional tour

d'horizon of the leading practiced academic professional economics visionary of the

twentieth century. And for still others it is the wisest compendium of names and titles

ever published in English (and possibly in all other languages) in the long history of the

discipline.

1.4 In the past there have been many treatments of the history of the discipline

employed as explanations of the development of economic theory. Indeed, one way to

explain the emergence of the Smithian and Ricardian virtual hegemony was simply to

recount how Smith had fused earlier writings, rejected some, and made others canon.

Ricardo, referring to Smith's 1776 economics masterpiece,7

offered a tighter type of

reasoning, and thus it seemed classical economics was assembled, if not actually born.8

The official 'registry of birth,' as seen by the British, was undoubtedly John Ramsay

McCulloch's The Literature of Political Economy (1840), just as Jérôme-Adolphe

Blanqui's Histoire de l'économie politique en Europe9

(1838) could be said to have been

an even earlier French claim—of course making McCulloch's either a collateral, if lesser,

relative or simply a Pretender.

There is a German lineage, as well. Wilhelm Georg Friedrich Roscher first brought out

his Geschichte der Englishen Volkswirtshaftslehre (1851) and then later in 1874 his

Geschichte der Nationalökonomie in Deutchsland, and his student, Gyula Kautz,

published in 1860 Die Geschichtliche Entwicklung der Nationalökonomie und Ihrer

Literatur. One could go on, but it suffices to indicate that not only Marx treated the

history of economics in Das Kapital (particularly in Volume One, 1867) but that object

of Marxian scorn, Eugen Karl Dühring, published a positivist Kritische Geschichte der

Nationalökonomie und der Sozialismus in 1871.

From a more 'modern' standpoint, I am tempted first to point to William Stanley

Jevons' decision to commission a translation of Luigi Cossa's Guido allo Studio

dell'Economia Politica (1875) as our 'cornerstone.' Cossa was so pleased with Jevons'

request that he expanded and partially rewrote his first edition for that translation. So it

7

The earlier (1759) masterpiece was the more carefully written, The Theory of Moral Sentiments. 8

A more properly systematic approach is to refer to that collector's 'gem of a servant,' The History

of Economic Thought and Analysis (1973) by Emma Fundaburk, to consider the wealth of efforts at

synthesizing the various approaches.

9

This book went through several successive editions. The fifth French edition is dated 1882, and

there was a translation into English of the fourth French edition (1880).

was that the 1876 second edition with a Preface by Jevons (and not published in Italian

until the next year, 1877!) became the template for many of the analytical history of

economics texts which followed.10

Until Schumpeter's 1954 History of Economic Analysis appeared, American (and

presumably British) economics graduate students generally referred to several 'old

standbys:' Eric Roll's strange mixture of pro- and then a-Marxian (to coin a neologism) A

History of Economic Thought (particularly the post-World War II 2nd [1946] and 3rd

[1954] editions) and Charles Gide and Charles Rist A History of Economic Doctrines

from the Time of the Physiocrats until the Present Day (translated into English in 1948

from the several [2nd, 6th, and 7th] French editions). More recently, that is, within the

last 20 years, Mark Blaug's Economic Theory in Retrospect and The New Palgrave have

been the principal authorities for graduate students. For economics undergraduate

students there was Alexander Gray's excellently composed The Development of

Economic Doctrine: An Introductory Survey (1931) and Henry W.Spiegel's The Growth

of Economic Thought (1971). More advanced scholars relied on monographs on writers,

schools, periods, and sub-sets of the topic (e.g. monetary theory, etc.). None of the

foregoing, however, is, in my view, magisterial—none attempts to synthesize a vision.

Since the appearance of the History of Economic Analysis two other particularly

authoritative works have appeared: Wesley Clair Mitchell's Types of Economic Theory:

From Mercantilism to Institutionalism as edited by Joseph Dorfman (1967, 1969)11 and

Karl Pribram's A History of Economic Reasoning (1983). Neither attempted to synthesize

a vision, although each sought to present an organizing theme, itself a 'Whiggish'

interpretation (I would not consider such interpretations really to be visions). I shall

compare their major approaches below.

The most important thing about Schumpeter's History of Economic Analysis is its

impact on the profession. Unfinished and published with obvious and identified lacunae,

it can not serve as a good reference guide. Yet, reference is regularly made to it. Why?

Although I will expand on this point later, let me say here only that it offers a complex

but not-quite-idiosyncratic vision of economics.

Schumpeter knew Continental sources, with which most British- and American- and

often imaginatively. Most of all, he escaped the usual constraints of having been educated

within the bounds of British Utilitarianism, and even though for much of his life he

apparently had a weakness for the effortless superiority of the English gentleman-scholar,

he was in the important sense an intellectually superbly equipped outsider.

1.5 In sum, then, the importance of the book is that it gives a vision of the

development of the economics discipline, a vision created by an unusually well-read

'outsider' (from the standpoint of most British and American-trained professional

economists) at a time when he shunned most professional company and was driven by a

personal ambition work ethic to complete a monumental effort explaining the relationship

10 The well-known text by Charles Gide and Charles Rist, A History of Economic Doctrines, was

not published until 1915.

11 The basic manuscript was the result of a student's shorthand notes; in that form it was sold in

1949 by Augustus Kelley, Bookseller (New York) with Mrs Mitchell's permission (extended to a

very limited number of sets) as Lecture Notes on Types of Economic Theory: From Mercantilism to

Institutionalism. Dorfman corrected and greatly expanded the material.

between what he called the economic science and not only other sciences but also

other social studies and philosophical disciplines. Flawed by its incompleteness (due to

the author's sudden death), there is, nonetheless, nothing else like it in the English

language; and even when one turns to other cultures, nothing has appeared which has its

appeal, if not its scope. Most of all, it is the product of an imaginative mind embittered by

a World War in which his adopted country, perhaps misled by an ubiquitñus Anglo-Saxon cultural penumbra (which he came to despise), was seemingly fighting the wrong

enemy. The book stands as a challenge (perhaps if it had been finished it would have

been as a rejection) to the way Anglo-American economists were accustomed to looking

at themselves and their craft.

II THE BOOK'S PART IN SCHUMPETER'S

LIFE

2.1 Just why Schumpeter undertook to write the 1914 Der Dogmen—und

Methodengeschichte seems to me to be less of a mystery than is the slant of its contents.

He was at the time a young man, perceived both by the world and by himself as a

Wunderkind. It was part of his judgement as well, perhaps, of his conceit, that he wanted

to lay out a schema for the understanding of the development of the economics discipline,

both as a science and as practiced as an art. Assertive in tone, it reflects an intellectual

confidence that was as yet essentially untouched by any serious career failures. But, if

Schumpeter was unscarred, he certainly was aware that others had been. Of them,

according to Swedberg (1991, pp. 91–3), he was greatly concerned about the opinions of

Max Weber, whose efforts to combine an overly abstract theoretical science of

economics with a comparably over-detailed history of events and policies had resulted in

a new 'discipline,'—Sozialökonomie.

Opportunity came to please him in the form of a request from Weber, himself, to

prepare a history of the subject of economic theory. Weber was undertaking the

organization and publication of a deliberately important collective handbook, Grundriss

der Sozialökonomie. The other selected authors were two eminent older scholars, Karl

Bücher and Friedrich von Wieser. Their presence, plus his own desire to ingratiate

himself with Weber12, doubtless affected the rhetoric in the book. And while it retains a

nominal tolerance for a kind of historical approach, it seems to me to be clear that this

was a concession to Weber's feelings and was more of a courtesy than a fully sincere

opinion. At that time, Schumpeter was generally putting his chips on abstract theory.

12 It succeeded: Weber became a strong admirer and a supporter when it came to Schumpeter's

applying for chairs. Swedberg reports, however, that the two once avoided coming to blows only by

Weber's stomping out of a coffee house. What caused such violence? Schumpeter was fascinated

by what was going on in the Soviet Union, and seemingly endorsed Leninism, as practiced. Weber,

incensed by Schumpeter's indifference to human cruelty, could not restrain himself (Swedberg,

1991, pp. 92–3).

This earlier book went untranslated into English until after Schumpeter's death, but for

most of the history of economics aficionados of the inter-Wars period, its existence and

(for those who could read German, its contents) assured Schumpeter of an extra degree of

professional standing. Yet, Schumpeter himself seems to have regarded it as evidence of

an unfinished product. Space limitations do not permit much dwelling on its contents (cf.

Perlman, 1982), but at the time he wrote it he was intent upon (1) drawing a distinction

between scientific economics and political economy; (2) showing how British classical

economics was giving way to 'schools of economic thought;' (3) indicating that the

future of economic analysis lay in the tradition of Walrasian general equilibrium analysis,

albeit in a 'dynamic rather than a static form;' and (4) insisting that the filiation of ideas

as well as economic policy rested best in the minds and hands of a disinterested cultural

elite.

2.2 By the 1940s Schumpeter was estranged from many of his Harvard colleagues. It

is popularly believed that this breach came about because of World War II and the

alliance between the Western democracies and Stalin's Soviet Union. More than fifty

years after the event, it is hard to reconstruct the many feelings influencing the situation.

Loring Allen suggests that the alienation may have had an earlier source in Schumpeter's

ambivalence regarding anti-Semitism and the Nazis; but many of Allen's judgements

seem to me to be facile and too easily based on hearsay as well as post hoc, ergo propter

hoc assessments. But, whatever the cause, Schumpeter withdrew from Cambridge and

concentrated on reformulating his ideas about the historical development of the

discipline. When the war ended, Schumpeter reemerged from his cocoon, but he was

never the caterpillar, much less the butterfly, he had been as a young man. He wrote

brilliant essays on Irving Fisher and Maynard Keynes; both of them were published

posthumously in Ten Great Economists (TGE), surpassing his analysis in the HEA. He

served as President of the American Economic Association in 1948 and in that capacity

delivered an address on 'Science and Ideology'. More to our point, he was asked to

deliver, inter alia, a eulogy of Wesley Clair Mitchell just after the latter's death (in 1950).

It was a

strange, idiosyncratic performance but, for the record, the written essay, finished just

before Schumpeter's own death, if effusive is also wise. The History of Economic

Analysis seems to have been largely the product of the bitter years leading to and during

the War. Swedberg relates how Schumpeter proposed the volume to the Oxford

University Press, and from the first it was conceived as a vision, a massive treatment of

the emergence of the scientific discipline. But, like many last great works of artists and

other writers, it seems to have been cursed by an evil star. What was written was done so

by a depressed author. It was unfinished when he died, and his devoted student and third

wife, Elizabeth Boody Schumpeter, who had brought out of chaos what order there had

been during the years from around 1938 onwards, sought to polish the manuscript as best

she could and to integrate as much as possible.

The task was extremely difficult. Schumpeter's writing method was disordered. Major

bits and large pieces were to be found in three different studies, and it was not always

clear which had been written first and which later. Much was written in an archaic

German shorthand. However, she persevered.

But the evil star's curse on the project followed her as well. She suffered a malignancy

during the months when she could work on the book, and she died well before it came

out. Several Harvard colleagues did what they could to complete her task, but committees

rarely can do as well as a single individual and, as I have indicated, Elizabeth

Schumpeter's own knowledge of the vision, surely greater than anyone else's, was far

greater than theirs.

Elizabeth Schumpeter also proposed the printing of a collection of his essentially

obituary essays on key economists, essays running from 1914 until no less than a

fortnight before his death. Her selection (TGE) combines a judgement regarding market

taste (which may explain the lengthy essay on Marx coming first) and one reflecting

Schumpeter's regard for the eminence of the ten 'greats' (Marx, Walras, Carl Menger,

Marshall, Pareto, von Böhm Bawerk, Taussig, Fisher, Mitchell, and Keynes) plus three

appended short pieces on Knapp, von Wieser, and von Bortkiewicz.

Ten Great Economists I find is worth noting particularly because of its lengthy

analysis of Pareto's work. It is canon that Schumpeter thought Walras the greatest

economist in the history of the profession. I suggest that a less conventional view is also

worth considering. In the end he admired Pareto as much or more. At the very 'least,'

Pareto was the worldly St Paul to Walras's spiritual Jesus.

III How THE BOOK is ORGANIZED

3.1 In the HEA Schumpeter sets out to explain how the discipline should be perceived.

Part I (3.7 percent of the pages) as it appears seems to me to be the most important. In his

1914 study, Der Dogmen—und Methodengeschichte, which was long on self-conscious

organization,13 Schumpeter's themes involve a distinction between 'science' (e.g.

scientific economics) and econo-political programs (political economy), and contrast the

roles played by disinterested 'consultant administrators' as distinct from venal

pamphleteers (cf. Perlman, 1983). The older Schumpeter set out in the HEA to do

something far more sophisticated. He sought to explain economics in terms of the

dynamics of the sociology of knowledge rather than under the more usual rubric, classical

epistemology. I feel that his exposition would possibly have been pedagogically easier

had he chosen to tie his thoughts to Pareto's Trattato di Sociologia Generale, with its

distinction between rational and non-rational systems. But their goals involving theory as

a means to understanding human meanings were similar and Schumpeter, in explaining

ultimately what shaped economics (and by economics he clearly meant economic

theorizing), stated quite flatly that first one had to know

13 Jacob Viner observed that this book was along the lines of the Cossa study (1954, p. 898).

economic history14 and statistical display and analysis.15 Given that background, one was

then ready to study theory. Schumpeter took pains to explain that much writing passing

for theory was irrelevant and even jejune; theorists poisoned their own well by making

foolish condemnations of empirical details and extravagant claims relating to their own

progress and prowess. Many theorists were intentionally ignorant of the fact that the best

theorists (like Newton) were skeptical (with reason) of being classified by theorists as

theorists.

Nonetheless, Schumpeter's rule of thumb was that abstract rules were to be derived

from and then tested against observed data. Although he refers to Marshall as a leader in

the practice of 'scientific economics' (1954, p. 21), it is also even more true that

Schumpeter abhorred the tendency of Marshall and the Marshallians to bend their

analysis in the name of ideologies such as free trade, utilitarianism, and so forth.

In a significant sense, Part I of the History of Economic Analysis seems to have been

laid out as a major contribution. However, as it was unfinished, it suffers seriously from

omissions. What Schumpeter had to say about his bugaboo—ideology—and his Golden

Fleece—a scientific economics—can be inferred from the written version of his 1948

Presidential Address. But what he had meant to say about his coming to grips with the

meaning of Weber's Sozialökonomie is not adequately specified, and in his conscious

eschewing of Pareto's sociological system (as we will note below, his long essay on

Pareto was written during the last months of his life) his views are left for me, at least—

up in the air.

3.2 Part II reflects Schumpeter's greatest relative strengths. It involves about a quarter

of the book's pages, and it takes up ad seriatim first the contrasting seminal contributions

of Plato and Aristotle and the amazing lack of analytical material associated with

Republican and Imperial Rome before turning to a splendid survey of the Christian and

Natural Law writers. The third chapter of this part is a reprise of his 1914 theme of the

consultant administrators and the pamphleteers—the former groped for a vision, the latter

for reward. His treatment of Smith is insightful but, nonetheless, harsh. Praise, such as he

gave it in this chapter to the English, was reserved for Josiah Child.

The fourth chapter is more generous in tone; in it Schumpeter's identification of the

qualities of the hero becomes apparent. What impressed him most was the hero's ability

to build an original system rather than merely to introduce a mechanism of thought.

Taking up William Petty and his associates, Boisguillebert, Cantillon, Quesnay and his

14 Swedberg notes the influence of Max Weber (Swedberg 1991, p. 184). 15 Schumpeter's view was similar to Lord Kelvin's; science involved measurement, even if it was

not measurement, itself. Schumpeter, alert to Hayek's disparagement of scientism, was amenable to

every discipline developing its own ordering of knowledge (not learning), and specifically physics

(Schumpeter 1954, pp. 16–18).

associates, and Turgot, Schumpeter, the first President of the Econometric16 Society,

eventually added (in pencil) Turgot's name to one chapter's original title, The

Econometricians.

There follow three chapters focussed on specific topics and subtopics; suffice it here to

list only the topics: (5) Population, Returns, Wages, and Employment; (6) Value and

Money, and (7) The 'Mercantilist' Literature. They contain much informative

information—names, titles, dates, and, most of all, the tracing of the filiation of ideas, but

they are mostly descriptive. Schumpeter, quite naturally, 'graded' the names—among

those getting 'firsts' or 'very high seconds' were Botero, Serra and Misselden, Steuart,

and perhaps Hume. For many, the most useful thing about this part is the integration of

Continental names (with what is for many readers limited to English) the British names.

3.3 Part III covers economics between 1790 and 1870. The initial three chapters cover

the plan of the analysis, a bird's-eye view of the economic history of the period, and a

marvelous survey of the dominant idea-sets of that era. Again, Schumpeter 'reviews the

troops' (his phrase), and identifies his heroes, including Longfield and von Thünen,

Cournot, J.S.Mill, Say, and Sismondi. Schumpeter then devotes most of a chapter (5) to

J.S.Mill. In chapter 6 Schumpeter synthesizes British Classical Economics, using

Senior's four postulates (rational maximization, the Malthusian Law, diminishing returns

in agriculture, and increasing returns in industry) as a convenient reference point or point

of intellectual departure. From there he continues in the integration of Ricardian and

Marxian thinking, Say's Law of Markets, and the concern with production and

distribution. Both chapter 6 and its sequel (7), 'Money, Credit, and Cycles' are Englishexperience oriented.

Schumpeter's treatment of British Utilitarianism is worth specific mention. He accepts

its centrality in the development of the Brtish classical system, but he does not accept its

validity. Accordingly, it should come as no surprise that neither Mandeville17 nor

Bentham has a tablet, much less a memorial, in his Pantheon.

3.4 Whereas it took three chapters of about 84 pages in Part III to introduce the

intellectual background (the sociology of ideas) for the period 1790 to 1870, it took four

chapters but fewer pages (about 74) to introduce the intellectual background for the

period 'From 1870 to 1914 and later' in Part IV. Even so, this Part is the one giving full

geographical sweep. Taking up developments in theory in Britain (he concentrates far

more on Marshall than on Jevons or Edgeworth), France, Germany and Austria, Italy, the

Netherlands and Scandinavia, the United States, and finally in 'Marxism' (if not a land,

certainly a 'cloud' of its own), he sets the stage for what he really wants to discuss.

Chapter 6 is on the Marshallian system; chapter 7 is on the evolution of equilibrium

analysis (partial equilibrium being seen as the product of Cournot and Marshall; general

equilibrium, albeit static, as principally the product of Walras). Chapter 8 takes up

applications as seen in the treatment of Money, Credit, and Cycles.

16 Schumpeter thought the word, Econometrics, philologically ignorant, '…it ought to be either

Ecometrics or Economometrics' (Schumpeter 1954, p. 209). 17 Hardly mentioned (two slim references). Hayek, by way of contrast, makes Mandeville's role

seminal in the development of individualism, utilitarianism, and even in the self-regulating market.

(See Hayek, 1967, Perlman, 1990, and 5.6 below.)

Schumpeter mentions with enthusiasm his colleague Haberler, and with less

enthusiasm his contemporary, Maynard Keynes.18 Bates Clark and Wesley Clair

Mitchell19 get short shrift.20 Irving Fisher (on balance) is treated with qualified

enthusiasm and at some, if limited, length.21 Instead, he sets out to glorify Walras, and as

I have mentioned earlier and will mention again below, he eschewed most but not all

lengthy discussion of Pareto. As Schumpeter was a man hardly consumed with modesty,

false or otherwise, it is puzzling why he did not mention any of his own contributions;

perhaps that was to be left to the last.

In my judgement, Part 4—because it was to lay the foundations for an understanding

of the meaning of dynamic general equilibrium analysis—needed much more work. My

guess is that, given the time, Schumpeter could have greatly expanded and improved its

exposition. But, I also believe that given the state of mathematics during the period

before 1960 and his own reluctance to get involved in further studies in mathematics, this

section was bound to have been limited.

3.5 Part V was to be 'A Sketch of Modern Developments.' As the manuscript was left,

it had a truncated statement of his plan, a comparison of the Marshallian-Wicksellian (an

essentially partial equilibrium analysis) approach, a discussion of 'totalitarian economics'

(Germany, Italy, and Russia), some thoughts about dynamics and business-cycle

research, and a slightly polished assessment of Keynes's impact on the profession.22 This

Part, clearly intended to be ultimately no more than a 'sketch', is too unfinished to be of

concern to anyone but those interested only in very preliminary drawings.